Murphy in Choice portrays Böhm-Bawerk as a champion of the time preference view of interest, but economics professor Jeffrey Herbener says Böhm-Bawerk clearly rejected the PTPT. In the first lines of Böhm-Bawerk's Capital and Interest he states what he considers to be the problem of interest: “Whoever is the owner of a capital sum is ordinarily able to derive from it a permanent net income which goes under the scientific name of interest in the broad sense of the term.” As Böhm-Bawerk makes clear in describing his theory, however, this way of putting the matter allows for both time preference and value productivity influences on interest. ... The PTPT, in contrast, makes no claim about the amount of goods being generated in production, but only about the net (monetary) income earned from trading present money for future money. It states that time preference will always generate a positive difference between the selling prices of output and the buying prices of inputs" (Herbener, The Pure Time-Preference Theory of Interest, 21).
"Böhm-Bawerk has once for all unmasked the fallacies of the naïve productivity explanations of interest, i.e., of the idea that interest is the expression of the physical productivity off actors of production. However, Böhm-Bawerk has himself based his own theory to some extent on the productivity approach. In referring in his explanation to the technological superiority of more time consuming, roundabout processes of production, he avoids the crudity of the naïve productivity fallacies. But in fact he returns, although in a subtler form, to the productivity approach" (Mises in Herbener, 72).
In the mid-1830s, the Irish economist Samuel Mountifort Longfield worked out the later Austrian theory of capital as performing the service for workers of supplying money at present instead of waiting for the future when the product will be sold. In turn the capitalist receives from the workers a time discount from their productivity. (Rothbard in Herbener, 63).
"We should note, first of all, that this theory is not necessarily vulnerable to the basic Böhm-Bawerkian criticism of all productivity-of-capital theories of interest. Böhm-Bawerk had criticized such theories of interest because they ignore the essential interest problem (as formulated above). It will not do to say that the machine yields interest (in the form of a flow of rentals that is greater than the cost of the machine) because the machine is physically productive (Kirzener in Herbener, 102).
"Interest is, in this view, the marginal productivity return on a scarce factor, viz., waiting. The Fisherian “productivity-of-waiting” theory emphatically recognizes the significance of time preference" (Kirzner in Herbener, 103).
Sunday, April 23, 2017
Thursday, April 20, 2017
Pure Time Preference Theory of Interest #3
The
productivity theory of interest is analogous to wages and labor.
Employers pay workers for the output their labor makes possible.
Similarly, if capitalists provide a capital good, the capitalist must
be paid interest commensurate with the increase in output that the
capital good makes possible. Murphy holds that Böhm-Bawerk
brilliantly refuted this line of reasoning. He quotes Böhm-Bawerk:
"I
grant without ado that capital actually possesses the physical
productivity ascribed to it, that is to say, that more goods can
actually be produced with its help than without. I will also grant
... that the greater amount of goods produced with the help of
capital has higher value than the smaller amount of goods produced
without it. But there is not one single feature in the whole set of
circumstances to indicate that this greater amount of goods must be
worth more
than the capital consumed in its production.
And that is the feature of the phenomenon of excess value that must
be explained" (Choice
227-8)
It
seems to me that Böhm-Bawerk attacked a straw man of the
productivity theory.
"Literally
to ascribe to capital a power of producing value is to misunderstand
the essential nature of value, and to misunderstand the essential
nature of production completely. Value is not produced at all, and
cannot be produced. We never produce anything but forms, shapes of
materials, combinations of material, that is to say, things, goods"
(Capital
and Interest
90).
Probably
critics of the Marxist notion of "surplus value" contended
that "capital produces value." That can be regarded as a
shorter way of saying "capital produces things that have value."
Böhm-Bawerk's interpretation makes it a straw man.
After
great praise for John Rae (Capital
and Interest
208), Böhm-Bawerk even chides Rae for conflating physical returns
with value returns, protesting that prices would adjust to normalize
the exchange value surplus or rate of return, in the technically more
productive processes. Rae could hardly have arrived at this correct
result since he lacked “the modern theory of marginal utility.”
(Herbener, The
Pure Time-Preference Theory of Interest 31).
While
Murphy defends the time-preference theory in Choice,
he apparently had a little different view not much earlier. "Second,
Murphy argues that if pure time preference theorists define time
preference in terms of satisfactions and not goods, then time
preference is neither necessary nor sufficient to explain the rate of
interest as defined as the intertemporal exchange rate of goods.
This criticism also misses the mark since in the PTPT the rate of
interest is not the intertemporal exchange rate of goods. With the
intertemporal exchange of money, pure time preference is both
necessary and sufficient to explain the pure rate of interest"
(Herbener 55-6).
To
be continued.
Monday, April 17, 2017
Taxes
Danielle Kurtzleben at NPR (National Public Radio) here reports on having asked people if they believed the highest earners pay a significantly higher share of federal income taxes than they did in 1980.
I clicked True. Kurtzleben says it is False. She's wrong. See here. The graph shows about 19% in 1980 and about 36% in 2011. Kurtzleben's "justification" fails, because the question is about share of taxes paid and her "justification" is based on rates.
P.S. After I posted the above and wrote to NPR about it, the NPR website was edited. It now reads: True or False: For the highest earners, the percent of federal income taxes they pay now is significantly higher than it was in 1980.
That better fits her explanation, but "percent" is more ambiguous than it was. Is that a percent of all taxes or a percent of high earners' income? It may also differ from the question that was asked respondents.
The page now includes: Clarification: This story has been updated to reflect that the question about taxes paid by the richest Americans could be interpreted in different ways.
I clicked True. Kurtzleben says it is False. She's wrong. See here. The graph shows about 19% in 1980 and about 36% in 2011. Kurtzleben's "justification" fails, because the question is about share of taxes paid and her "justification" is based on rates.
P.S. After I posted the above and wrote to NPR about it, the NPR website was edited. It now reads: True or False: For the highest earners, the percent of federal income taxes they pay now is significantly higher than it was in 1980.
That better fits her explanation, but "percent" is more ambiguous than it was. Is that a percent of all taxes or a percent of high earners' income? It may also differ from the question that was asked respondents.
The page now includes: Clarification: This story has been updated to reflect that the question about taxes paid by the richest Americans could be interpreted in different ways.
Saturday, April 15, 2017
Pure Time Preference Theory of Interest #2
Murphy's Choice uses
an example of a tractor to present
Böhm-Bawerk's
argument for
the pure time
preference
theory
and against the productivity theory. Böhm-Bawerk used
a different example, but the tractor example serves as well.
Suppose
a tractor is expected to yield an additional $1,000 of revenue each
year for the next 10 years before being junked. Böhm-Bawerk
in
effect argued that the only reason a capitalist could earn money by
owning the tractor is that its initial purchase price is less
than
$10,000. If the tractor would cost $10,000, the capitalist would only
break even. If the cost were more than $10,000, the
capitalist would expect to lose money.
If
the tractor cost is $5,000, then the capitalist would earn a 7%
[approximate]
return,
assuming each $1,000 is reinvested until the end of the 10 years.
Note: Assuming no reinvestment,
the capitalist could pay
$7,022
and
earn 7.00%. Solving the equation:
-7022 + 1000*(1+r)-1
+ 1000*(1+r)-2
+ 1000*(1+r)-3
+ ... +
1000*(1+r)-10
= 0
yields r
= 0.0700 or 7.00%. The
variable r
here is commonly called internal
rate of return. An equation of this sort
is widely used to evaluate capital projects.
"By
this procedure, Böhm-Bawerk
had
transformed his original question. Rather than asking, 'Why do
capitalists earn an effortless flow of interest income?', he could
instead wonder, 'Why is it that the initial purchase price of capital
goods systematically fall short of the future income their use is
expected to yield?' Against this metric, Böhm-Bawerk
measured
all of the explanations of interest that economic theorists had
offered before his own writing" (Choice
226).
Thursday, April 13, 2017
Pure Time Preference Theory of Interest #1
Murphy's Choice: Cooperation, Enterprise, and Human Action says a distinguishing feature of Ludwig von Mises's economics
is the pure
time preference theory of interest,
in which positive interest rates are explained by reference to the
fact that people prefer goods available in the present versus the
same goods available only at a future date. Most professional
economists outside the Austrian School would say that interest is a
return to the marginal product of capital, like wages are a return to
the marginal product of labor (the productivity theory).
Eugene
Böhm-Bawerk
in Capital and Interest (1884) classified and critiqued existing
explanations of interest. He called the productivity theory of
interest a category mistake. His own
theory was more or less the time preference theory of interest, although he didn't label it that.
Later
Frank Fetter (1904) offered a pure
time preference theory of interest. Mises
adopted Fetter's time preference theory with a twist. Whereas Fetter
regarded the theory as empirical, Mises elevated it to a category of
action.
Oddly
enough, Murphy says, "After explaining the Austrian approach to
interest – which has nothing to do with the productivity of capital
per se – we will see how the accumulation of capital goods
increases the productivity of labor and land resources, thereby
increasing income" (Choice
224).
Murphy
proceed to explain what Böhm-Bawerk
dubbed the naive productivity theory and and their critique of it. It
starts on page 225 of Choice.
The entire section is not available using the Look
Inside
feature on Amazon, but the argument more or less follows Murphy's
paper Why
Do Capitalists Earn Interest Income?,
available online here.
In
future posts I will briefly present the Austrian arguments for the pure time preference theory and against the productivity theory, and present my
reasons for not being persuaded that time preference gives a
full explanation without regard to the productivity of capital.
Monday, April 10, 2017
Murphy's Choice
Choice: Cooperation, Enterprise, and Human Action is a book that presents Ludwig von Mises' Human Action in a more accessible style. A reader with no prior knowledge of economics can get a basic understanding of the magnum opus of one of history’s most important economists. It's a good refresher for those who have read Human Action. It is also much shorter, 336 pages versus more than 900.
The first seven pages consists of praise from many economists.
The author, Robert P. Murphy, also wrote A Study Guide to Human Action, available for download here. I haven't read it, so I can't compare them. It is a little longer, 382 pages.
The first seven pages consists of praise from many economists.
The author, Robert P. Murphy, also wrote A Study Guide to Human Action, available for download here. I haven't read it, so I can't compare them. It is a little longer, 382 pages.
Thursday, April 6, 2017
Sports contests
I entered the Post Newspapers NCAA basketball tourney bracket challenge again this year. I finished at the 68th percentile among over 134,000 entries. That's not great but it was better than all but one of the 13 "experts" at CBSSports.com. I did better than Barack Obama on every round through the Final Four, but he beat me overall. I had two of the Final Four correct versus his one. He picked one of the final two teams and the champion -- North Carolina. Correct picks in later rounds count more.
Surprising teams were South Carolina, a #11 seed that made it to the Final Four, and Xavier, another #11 seed that made it to the Elite Eight.
I'm playing Fantasy Baseball again this year. It's a long season.
Surprising teams were South Carolina, a #11 seed that made it to the Final Four, and Xavier, another #11 seed that made it to the Elite Eight.
I'm playing Fantasy Baseball again this year. It's a long season.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)